1 Introduction

Linkages between Emissions Trading Systems (ETSs) are deemed a key element of the future climate policy landscape (Bodansky et al. 2016; Mehling et al. 2018).Footnote 1 Indeed, for many parties to the Paris Agreement, one of the instruments of choice to deliver on the pledged emissions reductions is carbon markets, 21 of which are in operation along with others in the pipeline (ICAP 2018). Against this backdrop, linkage has become high on the climate policy agenda because it has potential to unleash cost-efficiency gains and help ratchet up ambition. Although most jurisdictions with operating or planned ETSs have engaged in some form of linking negotiations, links are difficult to agree and remain few and far between.

Indeed, the multi-faceted nature of linkage as well as growing heterogeneity in market designs and governance frameworks pose many challenges to prospective partners (Ranson and Stavins 2016). First, discrepancies in autarky prices reflect different ambition levels or views about the desirable price signal (Fankhauser and Hepburn 2010).Footnote 2 Although a wide autarky price gap would increase attendant economic linkage gains, this may also raise concerns about rent transfer, equity, exported abatement co-benefits and so on, thereby impeding on the political feasibility of a link. Second, a certain degree of design harmonization is required to ensure market compatibility and avoid disruptions to the linked system, which also reduces regulatory autonomy (Jaffe et al. 2009).Footnote 3 Third, even when jurisdictions have compatible systems and are seeing eye to eye in terms of ambition, there are still risks that link outcomes do not unfold as anticipated. For instance, linkage creates exposure to ‘imported risks’, i.e., developments originating abroad that propagate throughout the linked system (Flachsland et al. 2009).

Therefore, forging linkage agreements that reconcile and accommodate every party’s interests is proving difficult and the most suitable way for interconnection may well fall short of a full, unrestricted link, at least in the near term. Two types of approaches can be contemplated to palliate the acknowledged difficulties in initiating linkage. First, interties through a common hub might constitute a first step toward further market integration, e.g. networking or indirect linkage via offsetting.Footnote 4 For instance, Jaffe et al. (2009), Tuerk et al. (2009) and Fankhauser and Hepburn (2010) conceived of a progressive mechanism of market integration via unilateral connections to the Clean Development Mechanism, envisaged as a common hub in the Kyoto era.Footnote 5 Second, permit trade restrictions might be established in the perspective of full linkage. According to Mehling and Haites (2009), «a bilateral link can be approached gradually; quantity restrictions could be applied to the other scheme’s units initially and can be loosened over time as the effects [associated with the link] become clear».

In essence, restrictions provide levers to adjust for the reach of the link and their potential is threefold. First, they can contain some link-induced effects (e.g., price variation or abatement relocation) that otherwise stymie link formation (Jaffe et al. 2009; Schneider et al. 2017).Footnote 6 Second, they can provide leverage in linkage negotiations through induced rents or revenues (Gavard et al. 2016). Third but not least, they can help gradually overcome some obstacles to full linkage while giving a taste of it, essentially facilitating negotiations by breaking down a lengthy linking process into progressive steps in the sense of ‘linking by degrees’ (Burtraw et al. 2013).Footnote 7 Our focus primarily lies on the latter aspect. Indeed, such a gradual approach and the various forms it may take have not yet been analyzed carefully.

We consider three main types of link restrictions, namely quantitative transfer limits, border taxes on permit transfers and exchange rates on permits’ compliance values. We also discuss two other forms of restrictions, namely unilateral linkage and discount rates. To evaluate their relative effects we use a partial-equilibrium model of linkage between two markets in a static and deterministic framework. Our stylized model is simple which offers analytical tractability and, crucially, enables us to compare all types of link restrictions in a unifying framework.Footnote 8 This greatly enhances insight and constitutes our first contribution.

No less importantly, our model has enough structure to highlight key differences across restrictions. In particular, we adopt a descriptive approach in comparing their relative implications in terms of cost efficiency, location and volume of abatement, price formation and inter-jurisdictional distributional aspects. By design, therefore, we lack a normative criterion for establishing a clear ranking between them.Footnote 9 However, we take our modelling results, along with lessons we draw from real-world experiences with emissions trading and linkage, as a basis for a policy-oriented discussion of the comparative merits of each restriction—thereby offering a policy menu, as it were—especially in their ability to initiate linkage and gradually scale up the link. This is our second contribution.

Restrictions are distortionary and drive a wedge between jurisdictional prices relative to a full link.Footnote 10 Hence, they create a trade-off between eliminating some impediments to linkage and undermining a fundamental reason for linking in the first place, i.e., cost efficiency. More precisely, by fixing the maximum authorized net permit transfer, a quantitative restriction provides a direct quantity handle on the reach of the link but the ratio of inter-system price convergence is unknown ex ante. Symmetrically, a border tax sets the price ratio but there is uncertainty about the resulting permit transfers. In both cases, the restricted link outcomes are comprised between autarky and full linkage, and aggregate emissions are constant. Just like a border tax, an exchange rate specifies the ratio of jurisdictional marginal abatement costs in equilibrium but further alters the relative compliance value of permits. Aggregate emissions are thus allowed to vary as a result of inter-system permit trading.

On the face of it, quantitative restrictions seem to be the natural route to full linkage between two quantity instruments. However, under a binding quantitative restriction two distinct jurisdictional prices coexist and inter-system transaction prices may not reflect marginal abatement costs, which can generate uncertainty about price formation and undesirable price fluctuations. The binding restriction also generates a scarcity rent whose distribution across jurisdictions is not clear ex ante. Quantitative restrictions can thus lead to uncertain distributional effects and weakened price signals, which may impair the transition to a full link.

Some of these aspects can be mitigated under a border tax on permits. First, since the price ratio is fixed by the tax rate, there should be less undesirable price fluctuations and transaction prices should convey better information on marginal abatement costs. Second, where a quantitative limit creates a rent whose inter-jurisdictional distribution is uncertain, a tax raises revenues collected by a given jurisdiction. Some distributional aspects of the link can thus be better managed and tax revenues can be seen as a form of inter-jurisdictional transfers which might help spur cooperation. Border taxes, however, may be more complicated to implement and pursue legislatively speaking, for instance at the EU level.

By altering the fungibility of jurisdictional abatement efforts, exchange rates can be employed to adjust for differences in programmes’ stringencies—and potentially other economic as well as non-economic criteria. In addition, we show how exchange rates, when skillfully selected, have potential to increase ambition over time. On the flip side, however, difficulties precisely pertain to the selection and subsequent adjustment of the exchange rate, which might possibly lead to environmental and economic outcomes worse than autarky.

Therefore, this analysis allows us to pinpoint comparative advantages and weaknesses for each restriction. Although there is no ‘ideal’ transitional restricted linkage, we finally show how experience suggests that unilateral linkage—whereby permits can flow in one direction but not vice versa—can be a practical way of gradually approaching a full, two-way link.Footnote 11

By comparing all types of restrictions in a unifying framework, we complement and provide an analytical underpinning to Schneider et al. (2017). Closer to our model, but conceptually different, Rehdanz and Tol (2005) and Eyckmans and Kverndokk (2010) consider trade restrictions as an expedient for importing jurisdictions to deter exporting jurisdictions from issuing additional permits relative to autarky—a perverse effect occurring when inter-jurisdictional permit trading in the future is anticipated as first shown by Helm (2003).Footnote 12

The rest of the related literature largely resorts to CGE-based simulations. For instance, Bernstein et al. (1999), Bollen et al. (1999) and Criqui et al. (1999) compared the economic consequences of different emissions trading scenarios to understand the opportunity cost of quantitative restrictions under the Kyoto Protocol.Footnote 13 In particular, Ellerman and Sue Wing (2000) demonstrated the monopsonistic effects and rents induced by restrictions on permit imports. More recently, trade restrictions gained renewed attention in the context of linking and networking. For instance, Burtraw et al. (2017) quantify the impacts of a link between the California ETS and RGGI with a 3-for-1 exchange rate in comparison with full linkage (1-for-1 trading) and Gavard et al. (2016) appraise the benefits of a quantity-restricted link between China and the US (or Europe).Footnote 14

In practice, restrictions have been used to regulate offset credits for ‘supplementarity’ reasons in the form of both quantitative and qualitative limits on compliance usage and discount rates on compliance value (Trotignon 2012; Braun et al. 2015; Gronwald and Hintermann 2016).Footnote 15 To the best of our knowledge, the closest example of border taxes on inter-jurisdictional abatement transfers was on exports of Chinese Certified Emission Reductions, whose purported objective was to split the CDM rent between the government and projects owners (Liu 2010; Zhu 2014). The distortionary effects, tax incidence and revenue potential of the CDM levy were also analyzed by Fankhauser and Martin (2010). So far, exchange rates have not been used to regulate uniformly-mixed pollutants but are contemplated in the context of networking. Usually they are advocated for non-uniformly mixed pollutants to account for the heterogeneity in both pollutants and reception points, and were for instance considered in the ozone-targeting RECLAIM programme (Tietenberg 1995; Johnson and Pekelney 1996).Footnote 16 Finally, linkage has sometimes been initiated via restrictions, as attest transitional one-way links integrating Norway and the European aviation sector to the EU ETS.

The remainder proceeds as follows. Section 2 sets forth the unifying modelling framework. Section 3 describes the implications of each link restriction analytically. Section 4 provides a policy discussion on the relative merits of each restriction with a special focus on the transition to full linkage. Section 5 concludes. An Appendix contains the analytical derivations and proofs (A), numerical simulations (B) and endogenizes domestic cap selection (C).

2 Modelling framework

There are two jurisdictions 1 and 2 with domestic ETSs in place to regulate uniformly-mixed pollution.Footnote 17 Permits markets are competitive and we abstract from market designs to single out restriction-specific effects.Footnote 18 We let \(e_i\) denote jurisdiction i’s emission level for \(i \in \{1,2\}\). For clarity and without loss of generality, jurisdictions have the same unregulated emission level \(e_0\) and binding cap on emissions \(\omega < e_0\).Footnote 19 They thus face the domestic abatement target \(a=e_0-\omega >0\). For comparability, we assume caps are enforced under autarky, full linkage and all other forms of restricted linkages. As we make clear below, it does not matter how permits are handed out for the purpose of our analysis.

We consider a representative firm in each jurisdiction, i.e. the aggregate of all firms located within its geographical boundaries (Montgomery 1972; Krupnick et al. 1983). Abatement costs \(C_i\) in jurisdiction i are increasing and convex in the abatement level \(a_i=e_0-e_i \ge 0\) with \(C_i(0)=0\). For analytical tractability and as is standard practice, these functions are equipped with a quadratic specification (Newell and Stavins 2003). Without loss of generality and up to a translation of the results the linear term is omitted for convenience and we let \(c_i\) denote jurisdiction i’s linear marginal abatement cost slope. That is, the higher \(c_i\) the less sensitive (i.e., elastic) i’s emissions (\( {\rm d} e_i\)) to a shift in the permit price (\({\rm d} \tau \)) since \({\rm d} \tau = c_i {\rm d} e_i\). In other words, jurisdictions are identical but for abatement technology and \(1/c_i\) measures jurisdiction i’s flexibility in abatement.

Autarky Compliance cost minimization under autarky in jurisdiction i requires

$$\begin{aligned} \min _{e_i \in (0;e_0)} \left\langle C_i(e_0-e_i) \right\rangle \quad \text {subject to} \quad e_i \le \omega . \end{aligned}$$
(1)

Because abatement is costly, jurisdictions emit up to their binding caps and \(\tau _i=c_ia\) denotes i’s autarky permit price. When autarky prices differ across jurisdictions, cost efficiency can be improved upon by relocating some abatement from the high-price to the low-price system. Let jurisdiction 1 (resp. 2) be the high-price (resp. low-price) system, i.e., \(\tau _1 > \tau _2\). Therefore, jurisdiction 1 has less flexibility in abatement than jurisdiction 2, i.e., \(1/c_1<1/c_2\) and the natural direction of the net inter-jurisdictional permit flow is from 2 to 1.

Full linkage Jurisdictional permits are fungible, i.e. mutually recognized as valid compliance instruments in either jurisdiction, and can flow both ways without limitation. Abatement thus occurs where it is least expensive. At the full-linkage equilibrium joint compliance costs with the overall emissions cap \(2\omega \) are minimized, that is

$$\begin{aligned} \min _{(e_1,e_2) \in (0;e_0)^2} \, \left\langle C_1(e_0-e_1)+C_2(e_0-e_2) \right\rangle \quad \text {subject to} \quad e_1+e_2 \le 2\omega . \end{aligned}$$
(2)

We let \(\Delta ^* > 0\) denote the equilibrium variation in emissions in jurisdiction 1 as a result of full linkage relative to autarky. As the linked market clears, the full-link equilibrium is entirely characterized by

$$\begin{aligned} C_1'(a-\Delta ^*)=\tau ^*=C_2'(a+\Delta ^*), \end{aligned}$$
(3)

where \(\tau ^*\) is the full-link equilibrium price. With quadratic abatement costs it comes

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta ^*=\frac{\tau _1-\tau _2}{c_1+c_2}=\frac{\tau _1-\tau ^*}{c_1}= \frac{\tau ^*-\tau _2}{c_2}\quad \text {and} \quad \tau ^*=2ca, \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \(1/c=1/c_1+1/c_2\) denotes the flexibility in abatement of the linked system. Overall abatement is the same as under autarky but is now apportioned across jurisdictions in proportion to their flexibility in abatement, i.e., jurisdiction i abates \(\tau ^*/c_i\) in equilibrium. That is, cost efficiency obtains and the autarky price differential is arbitraged away. The situation is graphically depicted in Fig. 1 where the thick-edged triangles demarcate the jurisdictional efficiency gains from the full link, \(\Gamma _i^*=c_i\Delta ^{*2}/2=(\tau _i-\tau ^*)^2/(2c_i)\).Footnote 20 Note that they are proportional to the square of the autarky-linking price wedges and that aggregate efficiency gains are distributed in inverse proportion to flexibility, i.e., \(\Gamma _1^*/\Gamma _2^*=c_1/c_2\).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Autarky and full-linkage equilibria. Baselines (\(e_0\)) and domestic caps (\(\omega \)) are common to both jurisdictions. \(c_i\) and \(\tau _i\) denote jurisdiction i’s marginal abatement cost slope and autarky permit price. \(\Delta ^*\) and \(\tau ^*\) denote the full-link equilibrium transfer volume and permit price. c is the marginal abatement cost slope of the linked market. Area \(\Gamma _i^*\) demarcates the efficiency gains accruing to jurisdiction i under unrestricted permit trading

Jurisdictional gains Our focus lies on efficiency and inter- (but not intra-) jurisdictional distributional aspects of linkage. That is, we treat each jurisdiction as a monolithic entity comprising the regulatory authority and the firms, which are themselves further aggregated into a representative firm. In the following when we refer to jurisdictional gains, we thus implicitly refer to the net combination of efficiency gains from linkage accruing to firms and the asset value created by carbon pricing (i.e., the monetary value of freely-allocated permits for firms and auction proceeds for the regulator). This simple structure will prove sufficient for salient divergences between link restrictions to emerge although we acknowledge that intra-jurisdictional distributional aspects can be key in assessing the relative political-economy implications of link restrictions.Footnote 21

In this context, note also that the permit allocation method is irrelevant as it influences intra-jurisdictional gains from linkage but not the net jurisdictional gains. Consider jurisdiction 1 for instance. As a result of the link, if permits are auctioned, firms would save \((\tau _1-\tau ^*)\omega \) in purchasing permits at auctions which would exactly offset the loss in proceeds for the regulator. In turn, the net jurisdictional gains amount to the efficiency gains \(\Gamma _1^*\) just as with free allocation. More specifically, with free allocation linkage is always beneficial on net for the representative firm but we cannot distinguish between ‘winning’ and ‘losing’ firms within jurisdiction 1—here, for instance, selling (resp. buying) firms that are worse (resp. better) off from the link-induced price decrease.Footnote 22

3 Relative Implications of Link Restrictions

3.1 Linkage with Quantitative Limits on Permit Transfers

Consider that jurisdiction 1 limits net imports of permits for compliance or alternatively, that jurisdiction 2 imposes a limit on the net quantity of permits it is willing to export. Either way, we assume the restriction to be binding and let \(\alpha \in \left[ 0;1\right] \) denote the allowed share of the cost-efficient, unrestricted transfer.Footnote 23 Abatement transfer is thus restricted to \(\bar{\Delta }(\alpha )=\alpha \Delta ^*\) and the level of abatement undertaken by jurisdiction 1 (resp. 2) is \(a-\bar{\Delta }(\alpha )\) (resp. \(a+\bar{\Delta }(\alpha )\)). On the face of it, a quantitative restriction should thus limit the reach of the link and associated impacts, i.e. its implications should be comprised between autarky and full linkage. As it turns out, there are more subtle implications.

The convergence in jurisdictional shadow prices is incomplete and cost efficiency does not obtain. The restriction \(\alpha \in (0;1)\) drives a wedge between these two prices denoted \(\bar{\tau }_1(\alpha )=c_1(a-\bar{\Delta }(\alpha ))\) and \(\bar{\tau }_2(\alpha )=c_2(a+\bar{\Delta }(\alpha ))\) such that \(\tau _1>\bar{\tau }_1(\alpha )>\tau ^*>\bar{\tau }_2(\alpha )>\tau _2\). This generates a deadweight loss \(L(\alpha ) \propto (1-\alpha )^2\) that is the sum of the deadweight losses on the importer and exporter’s sides of the market (triangles \(L_1\) and \(L_2\) in Fig. 2), the magnitude of which depends on jurisdictional abatement flexibilities. Specifically, because overall abatement is maintained, cost efficiency relative to full linkage can be measured by the index

$$\begin{aligned} I(\alpha )=(\Gamma _1^*+\Gamma _2^*-L(\alpha ))/(\Gamma _1^*+\Gamma _2^*) = \alpha (2-\alpha ). \end{aligned}$$
(5)

Even a stringent limit can bring about a high share of the full-link gains: \(I\left( 10\%\right) =19\%\) and \(I\left( 50\% \right) =75\%\). The less stringent the restriction, the bigger the overall efficiency gain from the restricted link, but the lower the increase in gain at the margin. This is so because when \(\alpha \) increases, inter-jurisdictional price disparities narrow down and net gains per permit exchanged decrease accordingly. In turn, the efficiency gains accruing to jurisdiction i reduces to \(\bar{\Gamma }_i (\alpha ) = \alpha ^2 \Gamma _i^*\).

There are two crucial implications of the inter-jurisdictional price wedge. First, jurisdiction 1 is willing to buy up 2-permits for a price of \(\bar{\tau }_1\) at most while jurisdiction 2 is willing to sell off 2-permits for a price of \(\bar{\tau }_2\) at least. This implies that transaction prices are undetermined in the present model (they can settle anywhere in \([\bar{\tau }_2;\,\bar{\tau }_1]\)) and that jurisdictional permits are not entirely fungible commodities.Footnote 24 Second, there exists a scarcity rent \(S(\alpha ) \propto \alpha (1-\alpha )\) of size \(f+g\) in Fig. 2 whose apportionment between the two representative firms ultimately depends on these transaction prices.Footnote 25 Note that the scarcity rent is at its highest when \(\alpha =1 / 2\) and exceeds the joint efficiency gains \(\bar{\Gamma }_1+\bar{\Gamma }_2\) when \(\alpha \le 2 / 3\).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Quantity and tax restricted linkage equilibria. \(\bar{\Delta }\) is the constrained transfer volume and \(\bar{\tau }_i\) the shadow price of emissions in jurisdiction i under the restriction. Area \(\bar{\Gamma }_i\) measures the efficiency gains from restricted permit trading accruing to i. Area \(L_i\) is the deadweight loss associated with the restriction on i’s side of the market. Area \(f+g\) alternatively measures the scarcity rent under a quantity restriction or tax revenues under a border tax

To pin down both the rent extraction and transaction prices we must specify something about bargaining. The market structure we consider is a bilateral monopoly and we assume a Nash bargaining game for the rent extraction (Nash 1950) with zero-value outside options where \(\theta \in [0;1]\) (resp. \(1-\theta \)) denotes the bargaining power of jurisdiction 1 (resp. 2).Footnote 26 In this case jurisdictions capture a share of the rent that is proportional to their respective bargaining power

$$\begin{aligned} S_1(\alpha ;\,\theta )=\theta S(\alpha ), \quad \text {and} \quad S_2(\alpha ;\,\theta )=(1-\theta )S(\alpha ), \end{aligned}$$
(6)

which also determines the permit transaction price

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\tau }(\alpha ;\,\theta ) = (1-\theta ) \bar{\tau }_1(\alpha ) + \theta \bar{\tau }_2(\alpha ). \end{aligned}$$
(7)

By contrast, the literature considers that the rent splitting ultimately depends on the way the restriction is set. For instance, Ellerman and Sue Wing (2000) consider the case of a competitive permit supply on the linked market with restricted demand and Forner and Jotzo (2002) that of a competitive demand with restricted supply. Typically, it is assumed that a restriction on imports, i.e., on demand for 2-permits in jurisdiction 1, grants monopsony power (\(\theta =1\)) to jurisdiction 1 which captures the entire rent. Symmetrically, a restriction on exports, i.e., on supply of 2-permits for jurisdiction 1, grants monopoly power (\(\theta =0\)) to jurisdiction 2 which pockets the entire rent. There is, however, no reason to postulate the existence of a link between the definition of the restriction and the market structure itself.Footnote 27

It is noteworthy that one jurisdiction may be better off from the restricted link relative to full linkage. To see this, fix \(\theta =1\), i.e., jurisdiction 1 is monopsonistic and makes the transaction price. We reason around the full-link equilibrium to analyze the effects of a binding restriction on jurisdictions’ total compliance costs, denoted \(TC_i\) in jurisdiction i. A restriction that is binding by a slightly enough margin leads to an infinitesimally small increase in abatement in jurisdiction 1 (\(\mathrm {d}\varepsilon >0\)) and decrease in the price (\(\mathrm {d}\tau < 0\)). Any such active restriction changes the total costs of compliance in both jurisdictions. In particular for jurisdiction 1,

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm {d}TC_1 = \left( C_1'(a-\Delta ^*+\mathrm {d}\varepsilon ) - \tau ^* \right) \mathrm {d}\varepsilon + \Delta ^* \mathrm {d}\tau . \end{aligned}$$
(8)

The first term on the right-hand side of Eq. (8) is positive and corresponds to the incremental increase in domestic abatement costs due to more expensive domestic abatement being substituted for imported permits. The second term is negative and measures the incremental cost savings on remaining imports. The sign of \(\mathrm {d}TC_1\) is thus ambiguous and depends on the relative magnitude of these two countervailing effects. When the restriction is lax (i.e., \(\alpha \) close to 1), the import price effect dominates the domestic abatement effect and jurisdiction 1 is better off under the restriction than unrestricted linkage. The converse holds when the restriction is stringent (i.e., \(\alpha \) close to 0). By a continuity argument there exists an optimal restriction from the perspective of the monopsonistic jurisdiction. Note that the price effect is absent in the case of price-taking jurisdiction 2 and the sign of \(\mathrm {d}TC_2\) is hence unambiguous

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm {d}TC_2 = - \Delta ^* \mathrm {d}\tau > 0. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

This corresponds to a direct income transfer to jurisdiction 1. By the same token, we can define jurisdictions’ optimal restrictions in the general case.

Proposition 3.1

Given\(\theta \in [0;\,1]\)jurisdictional optimal quantitative limits are

$$\begin{aligned}&\alpha _1^*(\theta )= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \dfrac{(c_1+c_2)\theta }{2(c_1+c_2)\theta -c_1} &{} \quad \text {if} \quad \theta \ge \bar{\theta } \doteq \dfrac{c_1}{c_1+c_2}, \\ 1 &{}\quad \text {otherwise}, \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(10a)
$$\begin{aligned} and, \quad&\alpha _2^*(\theta )= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \dfrac{(c_1+c_2)(1-\theta )}{2(c_1+c_2)(1-\theta )-c_2} &{} \quad \text {if} \quad \theta \le \bar{\theta }, \\ 1 &{}\quad \text {otherwise}. \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(10b)

In the relevant ranges, \(\alpha _1^*\) (resp. \(\alpha _2^*\)) is a decreasing (resp. increasing), convex function of \(\theta \) with \(\alpha _1^*(1) > \alpha _2^*(0)\), \(\mathrm {inf}\{\alpha _1^*\}=\lim _{c_1 \rightarrow c_2^+} \alpha _1^*(1)=2/3\) and \(\mathrm {inf}\{\alpha _2^*\}=\lim _{c_2 \rightarrow 0^+} \alpha _2^*(0)=1/2\).

Proof

Relegated to “Quantity-Restricted Linkage”. \(\square \)

First, because \(\alpha _1^*\) and \(\alpha _2^*\) intersect once at \(\theta =\bar{\theta }\), the two jurisdictions can never prefer a given quantity-restricted linkage simultaneously (relative to full linkage). Second, the range of relative bargaining powers over which the high-cost jurisdiction prefers a quantity-restricted link over full linkage is smaller than for the low-cost jurisdiction. This is so because the former gains relatively more from the full link than the latter. Third, optimal restrictions always authorize at least 50% of the full-link volume of transfers and the one under monopoly power is more stringent than the one under monopsony power (\(\alpha _2^*(0) < \alpha _1^*(1)\)).

3.2 Linkage with Border Taxes on Permit Transfers

A border tax on inter-jurisdictional permit transfers corresponds to the dual link restriction of a quantitative limit. That is, to each tax rate there corresponds a unique authorized share of permit transfers and vice versa.Footnote 28 While both instruments are equivalent in terms of equilibrium characterization in our deterministic framework, they will nonetheless differ in their distributional aspects as well as political and linkage implications. Without loss of generality, consider that jurisdiction 1 imposes a proportional tax \(\mu \) on 2-permit imports.Footnote 29 This tariff only concerns inter-jurisdictional transfers and there is no levy on domestic transactions.Footnote 30 Given \(\mu \), the restricted equilibrium is defined by the triplet \((\bar{\tau }_1,\bar{\tau }_2,\bar{\Delta })\) which, depending on the dispersion in autarky prices, satisfies

$$\begin{aligned} (\bar{\tau }_1,\bar{\tau }_2,\bar{\Delta })= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \left( \tau _1-c_1\bar{\Delta }, (1-\mu )\bar{\tau }_1,\dfrac{(1-\mu )\tau _1-\tau _2}{(1-\mu )c_1+c_2} \right) &{} \quad \text {if }\mu \in \left[ 0; 1-\tau _2 / \tau _1 \right] , \\ \left( \tau _1, \tau _2, 0 \right) &{} \quad \text {otherwise}. \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Again, the situation is depicted in Fig. 2. Equilibrium (11) is constrained to autarky if the tax rate is set at too high a level for given autarky prices. For instance, if \(\tau _1=2\tau _2\) then the levy on import transactions should not exceed 50% for some transfers to occur. The border tax thus locates the restricted link outcome between autarky (\(\mu \ge 1-\tau _2/\tau _1\)) and full linkage (\(\mu =0\)).

The tax is distortionary and cost efficiency does not obtain. Specifically, the spread in jurisdictional prices is linearly proportional to the tax rate and the deadweight loss rises at the square of it. Overall abatement is constant but some mutually beneficial transfers absent the tax do not take place (\(\bar{\Delta } \le \Delta ^*\), where \(\bar{\Delta }\) is decreasing with the tax rate). Additionally, the increase in the permit price in 1 relative to full linkage is less than the tax because part of it is passed on to 2 where the permit price declines. The magnitude of these price variations, i.e. the tax incidence, depends on relative jurisdictional abatement flexibilities.Footnote 31

However, there are two key differences from quantitative restrictions. First, a border tax allows for trades of permits whose jurisdictional prices differ as jurisdiction 1 pays a markup on each 2-permit it imports. That is, jurisdictional permits are fungible. Second, a border tax raises revenues where a quantitative restriction generates a scarcity rent instead. Distributional aspects of the restriction are thus clearer as the revenues \(f+g\) are collected by (the regulator in) 1 while under an equivalent quantitative restriction the corresponding scarcity rent is unclearly divided between (the representative firms in) 1 and 2.

Specifically, relative to full linkage the imposition of a border tax by jurisdiction 1 is unambiguously detrimental to jurisdiction 2. This is attributable to impeded inter-jurisdictional trade (\(L_2\)) and diminished terms of trade (g). Although its efficiency gains are reduced, jurisdiction 1 also raises tax revenues \(f+g\). It is thus better off with the tax than under full linkage provided that \(g>L_1\). This holds true for small tax rates, which highlights the standard trade-off between the level of the tax rate (\(\mu \)) and the width of the tax base (\(\bar{\Delta }\)).

Corollary 3.2

The optimal tax rate is\(\mu ^*=(c_1-c_2)/(3c_1)\)and jurisdiction 1 is better off from the border tax regime than full linkage if\(\mu \in \left[ 0;\,\bar{\mu }\right] \)where\(\bar{\mu }>\mu ^*\).

Proof

Special case of Proposition 3.1 with \(\theta =1\). See also “Border Tax-Restricted Linkage”. \(\square \)

3.3 Linkage with Exchange Rates on Relative Permit Values

We let \(\rho >0\) denote the rate at which emission reductions occurring in 1 are converted into emission reductions occurring in 2 through inter-jurisdictional exchange of permits. That is, one unit of abatement in 1 is worth \(\rho \) unit of abatement in 2. We define the linked market \(\rho \)-equilibrium by the following joint compliance cost minimization programme

$$\begin{aligned} \min _{(e_1,e_2) \in (0;e_0)^2} \, \left\langle C_1(e_0-e_1)+C_2(e_0-e_2) \right\rangle \quad \text {subject to} \quad \rho e_1+e_2 \le (1+\rho )\omega . \end{aligned}$$
(12)

We assume the aggregate constraint on emissions binds and let \(\bar{\Delta }_i(\rho )\) denote the variation in emissions in jurisdiction i at the \(\rho \)-equilibrium relative to autarky. Market closure yields \(\bar{\Delta }_2(\rho )=-\rho \bar{\Delta }_1(\rho )\) and the interior market \(\rho \)-equilibrium is characterized by the necessary first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} C_1'(e_0-\omega -\bar{\Delta }_1(\rho ))=\rho C_2'(e_0-\omega +\rho \bar{\Delta }_1(\rho )). \end{aligned}$$
(13)

With quadratic abatement cost functions, abatement unit transfers from 2 to 1 amount to

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\Delta }_1(\rho )=\dfrac{\tau _1-\rho \tau _2}{c_1+\rho ^2c_2} \ge 0 \quad \Leftrightarrow \quad \rho \le \tau _1 / \tau _2. \end{aligned}$$
(14)

There are two effects consecutive to the introduction of an exchange rate, namely fungibility of jurisdictional abatement units does not hold (emission conversion, or EC effect) and jurisdictional marginal abatement costs are adjusted for the exchange rate in equilibrium (MAC effect). First, for a given volume of inter-jurisdictional permit transfer, an exchange rate specifies a rate of conversion between emission reductions in 1 and 2, thereby changing overall abatement. Accounting for the sole EC effect, more or less overall abatement occurs in equilibrium relative to the benchmark. Second, the ratio of jurisdictional marginal abatement costs in equilibrium is determined by the exchange rate. Accounting for the sole MAC effect, an exchange rate induces a deadweight loss and modifies incentives for inter-jurisdictional transfers in a fashion akin to a border tax.

Proposition 3.3

Relative to full linkage, in an interior market \(\rho \) -equilibrium

(i):

jurisdiction 1 raises emissions i.f.f.\(\rho <1\)and jurisdiction 2 curbs emissions i.f.f.\((\rho -1)(\rho -\bar{\rho })<0\)with\(\bar{\rho }\doteq \frac{c_1(\tau _1-\tau _2)}{c_1 \tau _2+c_2 \tau _1} \in (0;\,\tau _1 / \tau _2)\);

(ii):

the additional aggregate level of abatement satisfies\(\gamma (\rho ) \doteq (\rho -1)\bar{\Delta }_1(\rho )\), which is positive i.f.f.\(\rho \in (1;\,\tau _1 / \tau _2)\)and maximal at\(\rho =\hat{\rho }\doteq (\tau _1 / \tau _2)^{1/2}\).

Proof

Relegated to “Linkage with Exchange Rates”. \(\square \)

When parity does not hold, jurisdictional abatements are not equivalent and aggregate emissions vary as a result of inter-jurisdictional permit trading. We see from Eq. (14) that permits flow in the natural direction provided that the exchange rate is smaller than the ratio of autarky prices. We also note from Eq. (13) that cost efficiency obtains only under parity (\(\rho =1\)) and that the \((\tau _1 / \tau _2)\)-equilibrium replicates autarky. Indeed, this rate makes up for the autarky price wedge and there is no incentive to trade. These observations delineate three trading regimes depending on the value of the exchange rate w.r.t. parity (full linkage) and \(\tau _1 / \tau _2\) (autarky) whose properties are listed in Table 1.Footnote 32

Reduction zone (\(1 \le \rho \le \tau _1 / \tau _2\)) The dispersion in jurisdictional marginal abatement costs adjusted for the exchange rate is reduced and the conversion rate is favorable to jurisdiction 1. The market \(\rho \)-equilibrium is depicted in Fig. 3. Controlling for the EC effect, this leads to less abatement transfers than is mutually beneficial in a full link. Controlling for the MAC effect, the 1-permit value is inflated, i.e. the exchange rate reduces the demand for 2-permits in jurisdiction 1 while increasing the demand for 1-permits in both jurisdictions (but jurisdiction 2 remains net exporter). Consequently, holding 2-permit imports constant, less emissions are allowed into jurisdiction 1 than under full linkage. In other words, holding abatement transfers constant, jurisdiction 2 abates \(\rho \)-as-many times more. These two effects combined yield higher overall abatement relative to the benchmark. Relative to full linkage, jurisdiction 1 emits less while jurisdiction 2 may emit more (\(\rho > \bar{\rho }\)) or less (\(\rho < \bar{\rho }\)) but overall, total abatement increases.

Table 1 Relative properties of the three trading regimes

Amplification zone (\(\rho \le 1\)) The dispersion in jurisdictional marginal abatement costs adjusted for the exchange rate is amplified and the conversion rate is favorable to jurisdiction 2. Controlling for the EC effect, this is conducive to more exchanges of abatement than under full linkage. Controlling for the MAC effect, the 1-permit value is deflated. Permits keep on flowing in the natural direction but since one 2-permit is worth \(\rho \)-as-many 1-permit more emissions occur overall. These two effects combined yield less aggregate abatement than in the benchmark. Relative to full linkage, jurisdiction 1 emits more while jurisdiction 2 may emit more (\(\rho <\bar{\rho }\)) or less (\(\bar{\rho }<\rho \)) but overall, total abatement decreases.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Restricted linkage equilibrium in the reduction zone (with \(\rho> \bar{\rho } > 1\)). The two curved dotted arrows rotate the line of slope \(\rho c_2\) to the amplification zone (AZ) and the inversion zone (IZ) and point outside of the reduction zone represented by the hull \(\left\langle e_0c_2,e_0c_1 \right\rangle \)

Inversion zone (\(\rho >\tau _1 / \tau _2\)) The dispersion in jurisdictional marginal abatement costs adjusted for the exchange rate is inverted and the conversion rate is favorable to jurisdiction 1 (even more so than in the reduction zone). The exchange rate sufficiently reduces the demand for 2-permits in jurisdiction 1 and increases the demand for 1-permits in both jurisdictions for jurisdiction 1 to become the net permit exporter. This regime is less cost efficient than autarky since abatement occurs where it is most expensive. Relative to autarky, jurisdiction 1 (resp. 2) abates (resp. emits) more. Since the exchange rate inflates the 1-permit value, this results in aggregate emissions higher than in the benchmark.

Note that aggregate efficiency gains no longer are a proper measure of cost efficiency since overall abatement varies with the exchange rate. Loosely speaking, the more distant \(\rho \) from parity, the bigger the dispersion in jurisdictional marginal abatement costs at the \(\rho \)-equilibrium and the lower the degree of cost efficiency.Footnote 33 An exchange rate affects both the size of the aggregate efficiency gains and its repartition across jurisdictions in the following manner

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\Gamma }_1(\rho )+\bar{\Gamma }_2(\rho )=\dfrac{\left( \tau _1-\rho \tau _2 \right) ^2}{2\left( c_1+\rho ^2c_2\right) } \quad \text {with} \quad \bar{\Gamma }_1(\rho )/ \bar{\Gamma }_2(\rho ) =c_1 / (c_2 \rho ^2). \end{aligned}$$
(15)

Aggregate efficiency gains decrease with \(\rho \) as long as \(\rho \le \tau _1 / \tau _2\), are nil at \(\rho = \tau _1 / \tau _2\) and increase with \(\rho \) thereafter. In addition, jurisdiction 1 (resp. 2) gets a higher share of these gains when \(\rho \le (\text {resp.} \, \ge ) \hat{\rho }\). Thus, with only efficiency gains in mind, jurisdiction 1 (resp. 2) would like the exchange rate to be as small (resp. large) as possible. This line of reasoning, however, does not account for the induced variation in aggregate emissions. In “Appendix 3” we show that factoring in this shift in emissions mitigates jurisdictional preferences for otherwise unrealistically large or small rates. Here, in the following special case, we illustrate an important implication of the exchange rate induced flexibility in overall emissions in terms of ambition setting as a dynamic process.

Corollary 3.4

Both jurisdictions are better off under full linkage with adjusted caps\((\omega _1,\omega _2)=(\omega ,\omega -\gamma (\hat{\rho }))\)than under\(\hat{\rho }\)-equilibrium with initial caps\((\omega ,\omega )\).

Proof

Relegated to “Linkage with Exchange Rates”. \(\square \)

This highlights that exchange rates have potential to increase environmental ambition over time. Indeed, consider that jurisdictions initiate linkage with an exchange rate that triggers additional abatement relative to autarky. Corollary 3.4 then suggests that, all else equal, both jurisdictions have an incentive to transition to full linkage with domestic caps adjusted so as to generate overall abatement commensurate with that under the exchange rate.Footnote 34

4 Policy Discussion and Comparative Analysis

We take our modelling exercise as a basis for a policy-oriented discussion of the comparative merits and political feasibility of each type of restriction. We further draw on real-world experiences with emissions trading, linking and restrictions. In order to both accommodate these facts and enrich the discussion, we will, at times, slightly deviate from the simple model of Sects. 2 and 3.

To start with, Fig. 4 is helpful in displaying the comparative effects of link restrictions in the overall-abatement-cost-efficiency space relative to autarky. Details on the calibration and additional numerical illustrations can be found in “Appendix 2”. The grey line describes the economic outcomes along the continuum of quantitative restrictions and border taxes. The black curve depicts relative cost efficiency as a function of relative overall abatement along the continuum of exchange rates. It delineates the reduction zone in the upper-right quadrant, the amplification zone in the upper-left quadrant and the inversion zone in the lower-left quadrant. Specifically, Fig. 4 clearly shows that both quantitative restrictions and border taxes affect cost efficiency but preserve overall abatement while exchange rates have an impact along both of these two dimensions.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Comparative effects of the three link restrictions relative to autarky

4.1 Quantitative Transfer Restrictions

Under a quantitative restriction transfers are restricted up to the authorized limit if binding; if not, full linkage should obtain. Thus, because transfers are confined within a predefined range a quantitative restriction is an attractive instrument if jurisdictions seek to have a direct handle on the quantity-side consequences of a link and retain a certain degree of oversight over their domestic systems. On the one hand, a high-price environmentally-inclined jurisdiction may wish to limit imports to avoid those link-induced consequences potentially pitting the economic gains from linkage against broader environmental or equity concerns. This would ensure that a certain volume of abatement occurs domestically (along with the ancillary benefits and reputational aspects thereof) or assuage fears about over-allocation in exporting jurisdictions that could dilute domestic ambition. On the other hand, a low-price jurisdiction may desire to limit exports in a bid to contain the link-induced permit price rise.

That said, some implications of a binding quantitative restriction are not as straightforward as they seem to be on the face of it. This is attributable to the coexistence of different price signals and undetermined transaction prices. Since one permit may have two distinct prices whether it is sold domestically (\(\bar{\tau }_i(\alpha )\)) or abroad (\(\bar{\tau }(\alpha ;\,\theta )\)) quantitative restrictions may lead to speculative transactions by creating perverse incentives for firms to make profits on secondary markets that are disconnected from abatement-related fundamentals.

A related issue is the existence of a scarcity rent whose apportionment among jurisdictions’ constituent firms is not clear ex ante. To mitigate these uncertain distributional effects, some mechanisms may be devised to allocate the rent between them. For instance, restrictions could be formulated at firm levels, e.g., as a percentage of firms’ individual compliance obligations. Alternatively, authorities could issue a certain number of licenses and require that firms attach, say, one license to each foreign permit they remit for compliance. Because the rent distribution may serve as a negotiation lever, linkage can be facilitated if jurisdictions are able to agree on how to allocate these licenses among them. While this parallel license market may offer a better management of the distributional aspects of the restricted link it does not determine how transaction license prices are fixed and, ultimately, the share of the total rent one can extract.Footnote 35 Additionally, administrative and transaction costs associated with setting up and running this parallel market might shrink the gross benefits of linkage. Note, however, that auctioning off licenses may limit these costs and redirect the rent from the firms to the regulatory authority.

Under conditions of uncertainty, we note that a restriction that turns out to be non-binding ex post might still affect permit trading and price formation. Indeed, Gronwald and Hintermann (2016) provide evidence that the probability of non-bindingness of the usage quota on Kyoto credits affected the offset-permit price spread in the EU ETS. Thus, in a context where abatement potentials, costs and baseline emissions have proven to be uncertain, a relatively stringent restriction has joint potential to bring about a relatively important share of the full-link gains, effectively contain the reach of the link as well as reduce uncertainty about its bindingness and related impact on price formation.

As a transitory linkage mechanism, quantity restrictions seem to be the natural route to gradually allow for unlimited trading between two quantity instruments. However, the ratio of jurisdictional shadow prices is undetermined ex ante, hard to infer ex post and transaction prices may fluctuate independently of fundamentals. Permit prices may thus no longer reflect jurisdictional marginal abatement costs, which is essential information in the political process of gradually scaling up the link in order to assess alignment in programs and ambition.

4.2 Border Taxes on Permit Transfers

Although there is a bijection between price and quantity restrictions in terms of equilibrium characterization, their distributional and other link-related effects differ. Because the ratio of jurisdictional prices is fixed by the tax rate, price signals are stronger as they better reflect marginal abatement costs, which is key information for regulators in scaling up the link. Moreover, a border tax raises revenues so that regulators have a better handle on some distributional effects of their policy relative to a quantitative restriction which generates a scarcity rent whose distribution between jurisdictional firms is unclear a priori.Footnote 36 Controlling for the induced deadweight loss, a border tax operates an inter-jurisdictional surplus transfer. In other words, taxes have a redistributive potential that may serve as leverage to foster linkage negotiations and can thus be seen as surrogates for otherwise politically unpalatable lump-sum transfers (Victor 2015).

Under conditions of uncertainty, the dual property between price and quantity restrictions would vanish (Weitzman 1974). In practice, this relates to the comparative advantage of having a fixed maximum level of permit transfers with a variable ratio of jurisdictional prices versus a fixed price ratio and variable permit transfers. Note that because a border tax concerns permit prices the link equilibrium will always be affected and potentially brought to autarky if the rate is set at too high a level. By contrast, quantitative restrictions may turn out to be non-binding, though this might still bear on price formation.

As a transitory linkage mechanism, border taxes may be more seamless than quantitative restrictions in informing a full-link scale-up and managing associated distributional aspects. Note that small tax rates generate a sizeable share of the full-link gains but do not reduce much of its effects. Conversely, too high a tax rate risks turning out to be detrimental (w.r.t. full linkage) even for the jurisdiction that collects revenues. Finally note that a border tax is a fiscal policy and might thus be relatively more complicated to pursue legislatively speaking than a quantity-based approach, for instance in the EU.Footnote 37

4.3 Linkage with Exchange Rates

As with a border tax an exchange rate sets the ratio of jurisdictional marginal abatement costs (MAC effect). Additionally, it also modifies the one-for-one compliance value of jurisdictional permits, i.e., jurisdictional abatement efforts are not equivalent (EC effect). As noted by Burtraw et al. (2017), exchange rates thus have potential to adjust for programmes’ stringencies even though cost efficiency is reduced.Footnote 38 Note that taking this line of reasoning to its logical extreme (i.e., \(\rho \sim \tau _1/\tau _2\)) implies the link would resemble autarky. Additionally, an exchange rate may also serve as a means to accommodate other economic criteria or types of political and environmental preferences.Footnote 39

Cost efficiency may be higher or lower than under autarky but is always lower than under full linkage. Moreover, aggregate emissions vary as a result of inter-jurisdictional trading due to the EC effect. In particular, the volume of unit transfers can increase, decrease or even be reversed relative to full linkage. Thus, as compared to autarky, the aggregate implications of an exchange rate in both economic and environmental terms could happen to be beneficial (reduction zone) as well detrimental (inversion zone). In loose terms, one can imagine that the reduction zone is likely to be targeted by regulators. In particular, if they prioritize environmental outcomes they should aim for a rate close to \(\hat{\rho }=(\tau _1/\tau _2)^{1/2}\). If, instead, they wish to increase market liquidity without bearing much of the other effects of a full link, they should set \(\rho \) close to \(\tau _1/\tau _2\).

Under conditions of uncertainty, however, selecting an exchange rate is likely to prove difficult which can lead to unintended and possibly detrimental consequences. The difficulty is indeed twofold. First, due to ex-ante uncertainty about programmes’ actual stringencies (hence autarky prices) it is complicated to select the rate right in the first place.Footnote 40 Second, it is also challenging to duly adjust the rate ex post since autarky prices that would have prevailed absent the link restriction are not directly observable. Although counterfactual autarky prices could be inferred, it would only be so with a lag of one compliance period at best. The risk of error and possible detrimental outcomes (e.g., of the inversion zone) in selecting the policy handle is higher than for the other two restrictions, whose associated outcomes are always confined within autarky and full linkage.

As a transitory linkage mechanism, an exchange rate has potential to increase environmental ambition over time when emissions cap diminution is not feasible up front. Indeed, penalized schemes—that is, schemes for which conversion rates are not favorable—have an incentive to raise domestic ambition provided that their domestic abatement units become gradually traded with parity. In fact, Corollary 3.4 shows that this ratcheting up of ambition would be in the interest of each party. Note also that since an exchange rate does not induce explicit rents, the transition to a full link may be easier than for a quantitative restriction.

4.4 Two Special Cases of Link Restrictions

We now discuss two additional restrictions, namely unilateral linkage and discount rates, as special cases of quantitative restrictions and exchange rates, respectively.

Unilateral (or conditional) linkage Unilateral linkage is a special case of quantitative restrictions whereby entities in one jurisdiction can remit foreign permits for domestic compliance but not vice versa. Should the unilateral link be established in the natural direction of trade its implications would closely resemble those of a full link save for the non-fungibility of permits. Conversely, the one-way link may also be inactive, i.e., an autarky-like situation persists. In other words, unilateral linkage can be observationally indistinguishable from a full link until until some uncertainty about the cost structure is resolved.

Note that unilateral linkage is thus of a conditional nature, which may entice jurisdictions to increase ambition. Indeed, imagine a one-way link between a ‘high-ambition, high-price’ system 1 and a ‘low-ambition, low-price’ system 2 whereby only 1 can purchase 2-units. In this sense, full linkage is conditional on 2 increasing ambition and note that the unilateral link constitutes a soft price floor for 1. Additionally, unilateral linkage can mitigate price uncertainty and distributional aspects (there is no scarcity rent) associated with quantitative restrictions.

A good example of active one-way linkage is the unilateral integration of the European aviation sector into the EU ETS as of 2012 whereby aircraft operators can surrender permits from the stationary sector (EUAs) in lieu of aviation permits (EUAAs) for compliance but not the other way around. Since 2013, the aviation sector has been short by around 20 \(\hbox {MtCO}_2\hbox {eq}\) each year, which represents about a third of covered emissions (EEA 2017). The aviation sector is thus a net buyer of EUAs and the EUAA price closely follows the EUA price.Footnote 41

Both the Norway-EU and aborted Australia-EU unilateral links were envisaged as initial, transitory steps toward fully-fledged links. In Phase I of the EU ETS and until the extension of the EU ETS to EEA–EFTA countries by late 2007, Norwegian firms could surrender EUAs domestically but not vice versa.Footnote 42 This one-way link originated in a unilateral decision on the part of Norway to help prepare for full integration to the EU ETS, e.g. gradual market design alignment. In mid-2012 Australia and the EU Commission agreed to link up their domestic ETSs following a two-step process whereby Australia would first be unilaterally linked to the EU (EUAs recognized in Australia, but not vice versa) before the link would become two-way three years later. For compatibility with the EU ETS, each step was contingent upon gradual design adjustments in Australia.Footnote 43

These three experiencesFootnote 44 indicate that unilateral links (1) can be established pursuant to unilateral or joint decisions; (2) do not require market designs to be as much aligned as for bilateral links; (3) may help initiate linkage while giving more time to bring schemes into sufficient alignment deemed necessary for bilateral links to be established seamlessly.

The elaboration of the RECLAIM programme also underlines the practical merits of unilateral linkage.Footnote 45 To account for spatial factors the Los Angeles air basin was initially divided into 38 zones without interzonal trading. This would have massively reduced the economic gains from using a market-based policy relative to command and control. One alternative was to create a single market with trading ratios accounting for spatial discrepancies but quantification of these ratios proved complicated and the resulting scheme altogether would have been cumbersome and unworkable. The final programme solely comprised two geographical zones (upwind sources, located near the coast and contributing more to elevated ozone levels and downwind sources, located inland) with interzonal trading allowed only from upwind to downwind sources (Tietenberg 1995; Fromm and Hansjürgens 1996; Johnson and Pekelney 1996).

Discount rates Discount rates are the unilateral version of exchange rates. That is, when jurisdiction 1 applies a given conversion ratio to 2-permits, 2 need not impose a conversion ratio to 1-permits that is equal to the inverse of the former. Therefore, discount rates may be asymmetrical, i.e., of different magnitudes depending on the direction of trade. When the differential in autarky prices surpasses the discount rate its implications are similar to those of an equivalent exchange rate (same EC and MAC effects) but full permit fungibility does not obtain. As noted by Schneider et al. (2017) this asymmetry may have potential to overcome some challenges inherent to exchanges rates. First, discount rates need not be mutually agreed upon so that jurisdictions can maintain relatively more flexibility in selecting and adjusting the discount rates they use. Second, if both jurisdictions were to implement discount rates higher than unity on inflowing foreign permits, then, whatever the realized direction of the permit flow, overall abatement and cost efficiency would increase relative to autarky, which is congruent with the ‘desirable’ characteristics of the reduction zone.

5 Conclusion

We compared various restrictions on permit trading in the context of a bilateral link between ETSs in gradually approaching unrestricted, full linkage. Restricted linkage creates a trade-off between eliminating some impediments to full linkage and undermining a fundamental reason for linking in the first place (i.e., cost efficiency) which justifies a temporary use of restrictions moving toward unrestricted linkage. This trial phase may allow to test the effects of the link and, by limiting its reach, assuage some of the induced effects and perceived risks. This also gives more time and flexibility for partners to reconcile their policy differences and bring their respective schemes further into alignment for a full link to be established seamlessly. A few years down the road, partners may decide to scale up the link. Otherwise, should trial not be conclusive the link may be severed.Footnote 46

We tried to keep the model as simple as possible to have a clear, unifying framework which, in conjunction with lessons from real-world experiences, served as a basis for a less formal, policy-oriented discussion of comparative advantages and weaknesses of link restrictions. On the face of it, quantitative restrictions seem to be the most implementation-friendly route to a full link between quantity instruments. In particular, they provide a direct quantity handle on the reach of the link. However, there is uncertainty about price formation and the distribution of the scarcity rent, which may hinder the transition to a full link. These aspects are mitigated with a border tax, which should ensure a better management of distributional outcomes, less undesirable price fluctuations and better information on jurisdictional marginal abatement costs. Exchange rates can be used to correct for discrepancies in programmes’ stringencies and have potential to increase ambition over time. On the flip side, however, they can be challenging to select and adjust, which might lead detrimental outcomes.

In order to hammer out a linkage agreement as workable and wieldy as possible, regulators can pick the restriction (or combination thereof) that best assuages dominant link-related risks and fits the negotiation and domestic contexts. As experience corroborates, transitory unilateral linkage may well strike a good balance between the ‘ideal’ and the ‘practical’ in translating economic theory into specific policy design elements.Footnote 47 In addition, the insights gained from this simple framework can help evaluate the effects of trade restrictions in the context of networked ETSs. An recent example is the ICAR Platform proposed by Füssler et al. (2016), which provides a structure to which ETSs may dock on a voluntary basis contingent upon their meeting a set of predefined requirements. Docked ETSs retain some discretion in the form of unilateral imposition of both quantitative restrictions on permit outflows/inflows and qualitative restrictions (e.g., discount rates) de facto assigning relative compliance values to foreign permits.

Finally, we identify three alleys for future research. First, although we treat jurisdictions as monolithic entities and abstract from intra-jurisdictional distributional aspects, we stress that this issue deserves more attention.Footnote 48 Indeed, the way restricted linkage affects firms and other jurisdictional constituencies is bound to shape regulators’ room for maneuver in selecting and implementing restrictions.Footnote 49 Second, while our model is static, it is of key interest to understand the interplay between permit banking and alternative link restrictions.Footnote 50 Indeed, each link restriction will distort firms’ inter-temporal decisions and market functioning in its own way. One can conjecture that, like in the static case we consider, unilateral linking may limit the amount of additional induced distortions.Footnote 51 Third, in a strategic environment, we underline that letting jurisdictions bargain over future linking rules (e.g., in the form of restrictions) rather than over domestic caps (that are strategic substitutes and thus prone to free-riding) may be more suitable for the emergence of voluntary cooperation through linkage.Footnote 52